You are here:   Columns >  Marketplace > Alas, Smith and Jez
 

Portrait of Adam Smith by John Kay, 1790

One of the unhappiest moments in my life was in September 1969, sipping coffee with other Oxford freshers after our first college dinner together. Inevitably, the conversation turned to politics and the events of May 1968 in Paris. I quickly realised that I was surrounded by lefties and, for the most part, by lefty idiots. Whether I liked it or not, these people would form a significant part of my acquaintanceship over the next three years. I had expected better of an elite institution, where (unlike me) the majority of my contemporaries had had rich daddies and been privately educated.

Given the large number of British baby-boomers who would have manned the barricades in Paris in 1968 if they had been French, and given the massive sales of Thomas Piketty’s sloppily-argued Capital, can Jeremy Corbyn’s election to the Labour leadership be that much of a surprise? The truth is that many people have daft socialist ideas as students and they continue to have more or less the same ideas as they go through life. No amount of evidence or experience can change them.

How then should economists react to Corbynomics? Some of it appeals to the worst in people, notably the proposal to introduce the right to buy for private-sector tenants. Presumably the calculation is that tenants outnumber landlords, and that there are votes to be had by helping the less well-off tenants steal from the better-off landlords. But Corbyn seems to have come up with something more interesting in his advocating a new version of “quantitative easing”.

In his words, central bank asset purchases should be “for people instead of banks”. To amplify, “one option would be for the Bank of England to be given a new mandate to upgrade our economy to invest in large-scale housing, energy, transport and digital projects”. The label “People’s QE” soon emerged, and it apparently has serious supporters. Last month the Guardian published a letter from 41 economists who said that Corbyn’s policies were not left-wing “extremism”. These included Professor David Blanchflower, a former member of the Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee.

Schemes for using the banks to fund public spending are not new. Many British socialists in the 1930s and 1940s favoured nationalisation of both the Bank of England and the commercial banking system, so that finance could “serve the needs of society”, as they saw it. (And let us not overlook the fact that such commentators as Martin Wolf on the Financial Times and Anatole Kaletsky on the Times welcomed the 2008 nationalisation without compensation of Northern Rock and Bradford & Bingley. The mortgage books of these two organisations have now run off at immense profit to the British state, but no compensation has been, or will be, paid to former shareholders.)

View Full Article
 
Share/Save
 
 
 
 
Postkey
October 10th, 2015
11:10 PM
"But Corbyn’s notion of a “People’s QE” does fulfil a useful purpose, of alerting the commentariat to the role of certain financial structures and institutions in maintaining long-run economic success. " useful, but: " . . . the latest example of left-wing idiocy."??

Postkey
October 10th, 2015
11:10 PM
" Why should the state not prohibit the banks from lending to the private sector altogether, so that all bank assets — and not just the central bank’s assets — are to pursue the desirable goals of social justice and ever-higher public investment? " Not altogether? Prof. R. A. Werner believes that the 'man-made problem' was the issuing of the 'wrong' type of credit. There is 'productive' and 'unproductive' credit. “Importantly for our disaggregated quantity equation, credit creation can be disaggregated, as we can obtain and analyse information about who obtains loans and what use they are put to. Sectoral loan data provide us with information about the direction of purchasing power - something deposit aggregates cannot tell us. By institutional analysis and the use of such disaggregated credit data it can be determined, at least approximately, what share of purchasing power is primarily spent on ‘real’ transactions that are part of GDP and which part is primarily used for financial transactions. Further, transactions contributing to GDP can be divided into ‘productive’ ones that have a lower risk, as they generate income streams to service them (they can thus be referred to as sustainable or productive), and those that do not increase productivity or the stock of goods and services. Data availability is dependent on central bank publication of such data. The identification of transactions that are part of GDP and those that are not is more straight-forward, simply following the NIA rules.” http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/339271/1/Werner_IRFA_QTC_2012.pdf

Post your comment

CAPTCHA
This question is for testing whether you are a human visitor and to prevent automated spam submissions.